Live Music 101 # 5: Promoters and risk – Emma Webster
Simon Frith’s Live Music 101 #2 examined the political economy of live music and defined two basic models of performance as a starting point with which to examine the economic transactions between artist, venue, audience, and promoter. In this addition to the ‘Live Music 101’ series of blog posts detailing the themes and ideas that developed over the course of the initial live music project, Emma Webster offers a model of economic risk that includes the promoter, and also defines three broad ticketing (revenue) models the promoter can use in order to recoup their initial investment.
Frith set out two basic models for the economics of live music: musician performs and as a result of the performance listener gives performer money (‘busking’) OR musician is contracted by listener to play for them (‘wedding band’). A more nuanced model to include the promoter would be as shown below, with the economic risk for the artist decreasing from top to bottom. The economic risk for the promoter, on the other hand, increases from top to bottom as the artist’s economic risk decreases:-
(It should be pointed out that if the artist is paying for production costs and in hock to a record label, the model becomes skewed, as it does if merchandise and sponsorship is taken into account.)
Promoters’ risks may not simply be financial, however, as promoters must also deal with personal and social risks including threats to their reputation and/or their own or others’ personal safety. A folk session ‘host’, for example, runs the risk of not being invited back if the sessions they run are repeatedly poorly attended or managed, which may then impact on their reputation among the folk community, while a promoter putting on a free party in a warehouse may even run the risk of being arrested, which may then subsequently raise their status among particular subcultural communities. In this way, then, risk may ‘constitute opportunities for benefit (upside) or threats to success (downside)’ (Institute of Risk Management 2002, p. 2). A promoter using the ‘pay-to-play’ model, may well be taking a low financial risk but potentially risking a high price in terms of reputation and trust.[1] On the other hand, while a promoter using the ‘guarantee plus > one hundred per cent of profits’ model is taking a massive financial risk, they hope to profit in other ways. Australian promoter Kevin Jacobson, for example, allegedly offered Bruce Springsteen one hundred and one per cent of the gross income for his 1985 Born in the USA tour, the argument being that it was such a high-profile tour that it was worth doing for next to no money simply for the international prestige garnered (Coupe 2003, p. 65).
There are also differences within different genre cultures regarding risk; for example, classical orchestral musicians often expect to get paid to rehearse whereas pop musicians generally do not. This also varies from company to company, however, and one event may contain a variety of musicians on different contracts. Scottish Opera, for example, expects its guest soloists to rehearse for no fee and receive payment only for a performance, whereas the orchestra members receive a guaranteed salary (Reedijk 2009).[2] Similarly, crew and touring ‘session’ musicians will often receive a guaranteed fee whereas the artist’s income is likely to be based on ticket sales, dependent on the payment deal.
Promoters therefore deal in different types and levels of risk depending on the type of show and the contract with the artist (if used). To recoup their initial investment, a major part of the promoter’s role is therefore to administrate the transaction between artist and audience (if necessary) and there are three broad ticketing (revenue) models the promoter can use in order to recoup their initial investment: ‘free’ (no door charge but promoter may benefit financially from the sale of other products); ‘donation’ (variable income based on what the customer chooses to pay); and ‘fixed’.[3] A free event potentially carries the most economic risks and must be subsidised in other ways, while a fixed ticket price should garner at least some ticket revenue. Within the ‘fixed’ model, economic risks may be further mitigated in a variety of ways, one of which is to charge a variable price for seats based on seat position, or ‘added extras’ such as ‘premier seats’ or meet and greet events.
[1] See for example, ‘Live and Unsigned Scam?’ (2010).
[2] As of April 2011, however, Scottish Opera’s resident orchestra moved to part-time hours (Miller 2010).
[3] Dynamic pricing – or the ‘airline model’ – is a ‘new’ ticketing model that, while not practised at the time of writing, may soon be in use and may well become the favoured model (Ellis 2011). Using this model, the price of the ticket increases or decreases in relation to the demand for the show.
References
Ashton, R. (2010b) MU says pay to play is okay. Music Week [Internet], 23 September. Available from: <http://www.musicweek.com/story.asp?sectioncode=1&storycode=1042646&c=1> [Accessed 6 December 2010].
Caldwell, C. (2009) Personal interview, Glasgow with Emma Webster, 30 September.
Coupe, S. (2003) The promoters: inside stories from the Australian rock industry. Sydney, Hodder.
Elbow’s Guy Garvey: ‘Something needs to be done about promoters ripping off young bands’ (2010) NME.com [Internet], 13 October. Available from: <http://www.nme.com/news/elbow/53403> [Accessed 6 December 2010].
Ellis, G. (2011) In conversation with Matt Brennan and Emma Webster. The business of live music conference, Edinburgh, 1 April.
Institute of Risk Management (2002) A risk management standard. London, AIRMIC, ALARM, IRM.
Jones, E. (2010) Festival headliners commanding huge fees. BBC website [Internet], 19 June. Available from: <http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/10356896> [Accessed 6 December 2010].
Live and Unsigned Scam? (2010) Leeds Music Forum [Internet discussion forum], 22 March. Available from: <http://www.leedsmusicforum.co.uk/viewtopic.php?f=7&t=25026&hilit=surface> [Accessed 10 December 2010].
Miller, P. (2010) Scottish Opera players looking for cleaning jobs. Herald Scotland [Internet], 6 November. Available from: <http://www.heraldscotland.com/news/home-news/scottish-opera-players-looking-for-cleaning-jobs-1.1066392> [Accessed 8 April 2011].
Passman, D.S. (2004) All you need to know about the music business. London, Penguin.
Reedijk, A. (2009) Personal interview, Glasgow with Emma Webster, 20 October.
BLOG CATEGORIES
BLOG POSTS BY MONTH
- June 2021
- March 2021
- February 2021
- December 2020
- November 2020
- October 2020
- June 2020
- April 2020
- December 2019
- October 2019
- July 2019
- April 2019
- February 2019
- January 2019
- November 2018
- October 2018
- September 2018
- June 2018
- May 2018
- April 2018
- March 2018
- February 2018
- January 2018
- December 2017
- November 2017
- October 2017
- September 2017
- June 2017
- May 2017
- April 2017
- March 2017
- February 2017
- January 2017
- December 2016
- November 2016
- October 2016
- August 2016
- June 2016
- May 2016
- April 2016
- March 2016
- February 2016
- January 2016
- December 2015
- November 2015
- October 2015
- September 2015
- June 2015
- May 2015
- April 2015
- March 2015
- February 2015
- January 2015
- December 2014
- November 2014
- October 2014
- September 2014
- August 2014
- July 2014
- June 2014
- May 2014
- April 2014
- March 2014
- February 2014
- January 2014
- December 2013
- November 2013
- October 2013
- September 2013
- August 2013
- July 2013
- June 2013
- May 2013
- April 2013
- March 2013
- February 2013
- January 2013
- December 2012
- November 2012
- October 2012
- September 2012
- August 2012
- July 2012
- June 2012
- May 2012
- April 2012
- March 2012
- February 2012
Hi Emma
Hope you’re well.
Note that the plus profit deals require a percentage. So, flat fees are typical at festivals as the percentage becomes too difficult to work out unless you start doing this per attendee i.e. pay x plus y per attendee over an agreed number of attendees.
Flat fees may also be seen as higher promoter risk as you’d be expected to pay more than down the percentage route i.e. the option is to pay a flat fee of x, or, less than x but with a percentage involved. The promoter is therefore gambling that they will pay the artist less as a flat fee than if a percentage came into play (is ‘broken’ as it is termed) due to the number of attendees.
Steve
Pingback: Live Music Exchange Digest – w/c 4th February 2013 |